A White Paper Response to Saskatchewan’s Climate Change White Paper

A White Paper on Saskatchewan’s Climate Change White Paper

Brett Dolter, PhD
Twitter: @BrettDolter

October 21, 2016

Introduction
The Saskatchewan government released a Climate Change White Paper on October 18th, 2016. The paper is positioned as an “alternative approach to Prime Minister Trudeau’s national carbon tax.”

It is no secret that the Saskatchewan government is strongly opposed to a national carbon price. In the press release accompanying the report Premier Wall asserts, “Make no mistake – a carbon tax will harm Saskatchewan.”

The Saskatchewan government believes that “talk about a carbon tax and cap and trade is the wrong conversation to be having” in Canada and seeks to shift the national conversation to “one that has a global perspective and a focus on innovation.”

But for this White Paper to truly shift the conversation on carbon pricing in Canada one would imagine it must do two of three things:

  1. Show carbon pricing to be ineffective; or
  2. Show carbon pricing to be harmful; and
  3. Offer superior alternative policies.

Has the White Paper succeeded?

Ineffective Tax?
In making its “Case Against a Carbon Tax” the White Paper invokes BC’s Carbon Tax. Here is a passage from page 27:
 blogfigure1(Saskatchewan White Paper, p. 27)

In support of this “resounding no” to Saskatchewan’s questions, the White Paper cites a blog post by CCPA economist Marc Lee and a Policy Options article by SFU economist Mark Jaccard. Let’s take a closer look at both of their arguments.

In his blog post, Lee argues that the effectiveness of the BC carbon tax has been “overstated by people who love carbon taxes.” His analysis looks at trends in average emissions per capita and he finds that emissions in BC have not decreased substantially with the introduction of the tax. Lee doesn’t, however, conduct a controlled econometric analysis to ask – holding other factors constant – has the carbon tax had an effect on BC emissions?

Other researchers have conducted careful economic analysis to understand the impact of the BC carbon tax. The New York Time article quoted in the White Paper contains a link to this research paper by Brian Murray and Nicholas Rivers. Summarizing several studies of BC’s carbon tax, Murray and Rivers (2015) offer a nuanced yes to Saskatchewan’s two important questions:

“Empirical and simulation models suggest that the (carbon) tax has reduced emissions in the province by between 5% and 15% since being implemented. At the same time, models show that the tax has had negligible effects on the aggregate economy, despite some evidence that certain emissions-intensive sectors face challenges”
(Murray and Rivers, 2015)

UBC Economics Professors Werner Antweiler and Sumeet Gulati confirm this finding in the transportation sector in their working paper Frugal Cars or Frugal Drivers? How Carbon and Fuel Taxes Influence the Choice and Use of Cars. Antweiler and Gulati conclude that “without BC’s carbon tax fuel demand per capita would be 7% higher, and the average vehicle’s fuel efficiency would be 4% lower.”

Lee’s post is far from the smoking gun Saskatchewan needs to make its case against carbon pricing. It does not prove the carbon tax ineffective and Lee himself is not against carbon pricing. Instead, Lee writes (in the same blog post), “A well-designed carbon tax can be the engine of a green industrial revolution” and, “To be truly effective, carbon taxes will need to be much higher than BC’s current rates”.

Mark Jaccard’s Policy Options article offers a different perspective. As of late, Jaccard has taken the position that carbon pricing is unlikely to be politically popular. Jaccard has never once argued that carbon pricing is ineffective, only that it might displease voters. Here is an excerpt from the Jaccard Policy Options article cited in the Saskatchewan White Paper:

“The reality is that significant emissions reductions will happen only if we rapidly switch to zero- and partially-zero-emissions technologies. Fortunately, these are now commercially available. But they won’t be widely adopted unless technologies that burn coal, oil and natural gas are phased out by regulations or made costly to operate by carbon pricing. The latter can be either a carbon tax, as in British Columbia, or the price of tradable CO2 permits under an emissions cap, as in Quebec.

Most important of all, Trudeau must understand that relying solely on one of these two forms of carbon pricing to achieve even the seemingly modest Harper target may cost him his job. While carbon pricing has become a mantra for economists, environmentalists, academics, celebrities, media pundits and even corporate heads, none of these people needs to get reelected. For politicians with survival instincts, it’s a different game.”

This is not an argument against the effectiveness of carbon pricing. Instead it is free political advice for Justin Trudeau.

Since that February Policy Options paper Jaccard has continued to build on his political acceptability argument. In a recent working paper with co-authors Mikela Hein and Tiffany Vass, Jaccard argues that flexible regulations can achieve reductions at a lower political cost than carbon pricing.

Canadian Carbon Pricing Proposals and Policies
blogfigure2

Using carbon pricing alone Jaccard et al (2016) calculate that Canada would require a price of $160/tonne CO2 to meet the 2030 reduction target. An alternative would be to use a suite of “flexible regulations” such as a partial-zero-emission-vehicle standard for personal vehicles, zero-emission transit vehicles, performance standards for industry, a nation-wide coal phase-out by 2030 (save for plants with carbon capture and storage – CCS), and a requirement that thermal provinces achieve 90% emissions-free electricity by 2030. With these flexible regulations the carbon price would only need to escalate to $40/tonne by 2030 (the Jaccard et al. line in the figure above).

These flexible regulations impose costs, but, so the Jaccard theory goes, these costs can be buried out of sight of the electorate.

Saskatchewan has experience with the cost of regulations. The province recently responded to the federal coal-fired electricity regulation by equipping the Boundary Dam III coal plant with carbon capture and storage (CCS) technology. There was a hefty price-tag: $1.5 billion for 110 Megawatts of electricity capacity. A quick calculation reveals that the cost of using CCS to meet the federal regulation implies a carbon price of $60/tonne CO2e relative to a new conventional coal plant (see table below).

The Cost of the CCS Response to the Federal Coal-Fired Regulation
blogimage3
(author’s calculations)

Will voters notice the increase to their electricity bills any less when it is caused by regulation? Maybe. But it still does not make the argument that carbon pricing is ineffective.

As Jaccard et al (2016) write, flexible regulations “will be less economically efficient” than carbon pricing. This means that we will pay more for emissions reductions achieved with flexible regulations than we would for reductions achieved with a carbon pricing policy. The career-minded politician would just have to hope the voters won’t notice…

Harmful Tax?
Will a carbon pricing policy harm Saskatchewan as Premier Wall has suggested?

As evidence of harm, the White Paper presents a chart showing how much each sector would have to pay under a $50/tonne carbon tax (see chart below). Adding the totals together, the White Paper estimates $2.5 billion worth of carbon charges in Saskatchewan.

blogfigure4
Figure from Government of Saskatchewan (2016) Climate Change White Paper. Available on-line at: http://www.saskatchewan.ca/government/news-and-media/2016/october/18/climate-change-plan. (p. 25)

But if $2.5 billion in carbon taxation is collected in Saskatchewan where does this money go? Not to the federal government. They have promised to leave all of the carbon revenues with the provinces. So, unless the Saskatchewan government burns the cash on the front steps of the legislative building, they would have $2.5 billion to spend.

How should this carbon revenue be used?

If Saskatchewan took a fee-and-dividend approach, the government could send a $2172 cheque to every woman, man and child in the province.

If Saskatchewan wanted to take a double-dividend approach, it could reduce taxes by 36% across the board (the total forecast tax revenue from personal, corporate, sales, and property tax is $6.9 billion for 2016-17).

If the province wanted to fill in the estimated $454 million deficit it could do so.

Or the province could give the money right back to the companies and individuals paying the tax. In the chart above, SaskPower pays $757 million/year for carbon emissions in the electricity sector. If this money went right back to SaskPower, in two years it would have the $1.5 billion required to pay for Boundary Dam III. In two more years it would have another $1.5 billion. What investments could SaskPower make in the following years to reduce its emissions? How much energy conservation could be achieved with a $750 million budget for conservation initiatives?

More strategically, Saskatchewan could use some of the revenues to address competitiveness issues for ‘emissions-intensive, trade-exposed’ (EITE) industries like potash, agriculture, and oil and gas. In his Op-Ed to the Globe and Mail Premier Wall notes that “Saskatchewan has a disproportionate share of Canada’s trade-exposed industrial sectors.” A report from the Ecofiscal Commission confirms that Saskatchewan’s emissions-intensive industries are more trade-exposed than other provinces (see figure below). One idea from the EcoFiscal commission is to offer output rebates to these EITE industries. The right incentives are then in place to maintain competitiveness; companies must pay for their emissions, but are rewarded for their output.

blogfigure5
Figure from: Elizabeth Beale, Dale Beugin, Bev Dahlby, Don Drummond, Nancy Olewiler, Christopher Ragan (2015) Provincial Carbon Pricing and Competitiveness Pressures: Guidelines for Business and Policymakers. Ecofiscal Commission. Available on-line at: https://ecofiscal.ca/wp-content/uploads/2015/11/Ecofiscal-Commission-Carbon-Pricing-Competitiveness-Report-November-2015.pdf.

These are just options for spending the revenue from a carbon tax. But the federal government has not prescribed a carbon tax; they are introducing a national carbon price. Ontario and Quebec meet the carbon price requirement with their cap-and-trade systems. In their report for Clean Prosperity, Chris Bataille and Dave Sawyer model the possibility of Saskatchewan meeting the national carbon price with a hybrid system that would include a carbon tax on buildings, transport and light industry, and a “nationally tradeable intensity standard and output-based allocations (OBA) for the EITE (trade-exposed) industries.”

An intensity standard would require trade-exposed industries to improve the emissions intensity of their output. For example, in the potash industry, GHG emissions per tonne of potash might have to decrease by 20% by 2017. If a firm fails to improve their performance they pay a fee for every tonne of GHG emissions that is above their performance target. This means trade-exposed industries don’t have to pay for every tonne of GHGs they produce, which lowers the cost of the regulation, but they have a strong incentive to achieve reductions. This is the plan neighbouring Alberta is putting into place with their Climate Leadership Plan. It is also not so different from the plan Saskatchewan introduced in 2009 with Bill 95 ‘An Act respecting the Management and Reduction of Greenhouse Gases and Adaptation to Climate Change’. Seven years after its first reading Bill 95 has still not been enacted.

In their analysis, Bataille and Sawyer find that Saskatchewan would do well under a hybrid climate policy system. GHG emissions would be reduced by 33% by 2030, and GDP would actually increase by 4.23% over the reference case (see figure below). This outcome depends on Saskatchewan hooking into a national system where industries that can beat their performance targets can then sell those credits to companies in the rest of Canada. According to Bataille and Sawyer’s model, there is low-hanging fruit to be picked in Saskatchewan, and it would be cheaper for some firms outside of the province to pay for reductions in Saskatchewan than it would be to reduce their own emissions. The resulting revenues could be an economic boost for Saskatchewan.

blogfigure6
Figure from: Chris Bataille and Dave Sawyer (2016) Canadian Carbon Pricing Pathways: The economic and emission outcomes of leading policies. Final Report September 15, 2016. Available on-line at: http://www.enviroeconomics.org/single-post/2016/09/06/Assessing-Canadian-Carbon-Pricing-Pathways.

The White Paper presents an incomplete analysis of the impact of carbon pricing on Saskatchewan. It focuses on the costs of a carbon price without considering the beneficial uses of the revenues. It ignores the possibility of a cap-and-trade approach to carbon pricing, except to note that permit prices are low and unpredictable in the California and European markets. And it fails to explore hybrid approaches, such as the approach proposed by Bataille and Sawyer, which actually show Saskatchewan benefitting from Canadian climate action.

Very few things in life appear desirable when we focus only on the costs (why get married when a ceremony and reception will cost thousands of dollars?) A more robust analysis would outline the opportunities that carbon pricing could bring to the province.

Alternative Policies
At the very least, an effective White Paper should introduce captivating new ideas for reducing Saskatchewan’s emissions. Has the White Paper done so? Here is my analysis of four of the ideas proposed in the White Paper. You be the judge as to whether these are likely to shift the national conversation.

Idea 1: Saskatchewan should receive 375 Mt of credit for exporting uranium

The White Paper argues that Saskatchewan exports of uranium lower global GHG emissions by replacing coal plants with nuclear power plants. Let’s accept this claim, but then let’s think through the consequences. If Saskatchewan receives 375 Mt of credit for exporting uranium, is Canada willing to own 627 Mt of GHGs from exported oil & gas? True, Saskatchewan’s oil and gas exports only account for about 100 Mt of emissions, but Alberta would then be on the hook for much of the remaining 527 Mt. Asking for credits for uranium opens a Pandora’s box of global GHG accounting issues that the Government of Saskatchewan would be wise to avoid.

blogfigure7
(author’s calculations, see below for assumptions)

blogfigure8

Idea 2: Sell carbon capture and storage to the world

The White Paper positions Saskatchewan as a small portion of global emissions (more on this to come), but a leader in carbon capture and storage (CCS) technology. As the White Paper asserts, “We (Saskatchewan) can help the world clean up coal-fired electricity generation as the world shifts to newer technologies” (p. 15).

This may very well be true. Equipping coal plants in China and India with CCS would reduce global emissions. It would be great if Saskatchewan could play a role in that. But what would lead these other countries to decide to introduce CCS when the technology is so expensive? The elephant in the room is a global carbon price. We can see even in Saskatchewan how carbon pricing shifts the comparable economics of electricity generation sources (see figure below). The green bars in the figure below show how a $50/tonne carbon price makes conventional coal more expensive, and improves the economics of CCS.

blogimage9
(Source: author’s calculations)

How can we achieve a global carbon price? At the bare minimum we would expect that wealthy countries like Canada would lead by example and adopt one first. Saskatchewan’s opposition to carbon pricing may be getting in the way of the province’s CCS export strategy.

Idea 3: The federal government leads the development of a small, modular nuclear reactor

The Saskatchewan government is an advocate of nuclear power. After the 2009 Uranium Development Partnership (UDP) consultation they backed away from the idea of building a nuclear power plant in Saskatchewan, but the dream has not died. The Saskatchewan government has since mused of building ‘small, modular nuclear reactors’ in the province. These reactors would be small enough to integrate onto the provincial grid, likely 300 megawatts (MW) or smaller. Problematically, these reactors don’t exist in commercial form. So, the White Paper asks the federal government to create one, “Saskatchewan calls on the federal government to take a leading role in a program to develop a small reactor that could be deployable in Canada and all over the world.” It is easy for a province to ask the federal government to foot the bill for a provincial priority (note: this ‘cap-in-hand’ policy is materially different from a ‘cap-and-trade’ policy). But how much would the development of this reactor cost? And didn’t the federal government divest from Atomic Energy Corporation Limited (AECL) in 2011 to cut its losses in this area? Saskatchewan has paid a high price to pioneer CCS technology. Does Saskatchewan (or Canada) want to play the Guinea pig for a second, capital-intensive power generation technology?

Idea 4: Saskatchewan is a small contributor to global emissions

The White Paper states, “that Canada’s national emissions represent less than two percent of the global total.” The figure below, featured in the accompanying press release, emphasizes Saskatchewan’s relatively small contribution to global emissions reduction efforts by comparing Saskatchewan’s reduction target to emissions from 2400 planned coal plants.

blogimage10
(Source: Government of Saskatchewan website: http://www.saskatchewan.ca/government/news-and-media/2016/october/18/climate-change-plan)

As noted above, part of the province’s argument is that CCS can help reduce coal emissions around the globe. But, another strategic aspect of the image above is to drive home the point that Saskatchewan is a small contributor to a global problem.

This is less a policy idea and more of a way of re-framing Saskatchewan’s responsibilities. But, it is possible to generate a similarly uneven looking chart with a very different frame. The figure below illustrates Saskatchewan’s contribution to global emissions relative to our population (per capita GHG emissions). In this chart we see that Canada’s share of global emissions is four times higher than its share of the world’s population. Saskatchewan’s share of GHGs is over 13 times higher than its share of population. This provides an international fairness argument for Canada and Saskatchewan taking strong action to reduce GHG emissions at home. We are polluting beyond our fair share.

blogimage11

Region Population Emissions (Mt CO2e) Per Capita Emissions (tonnes CO2e/person)
Canada 36,286,425 732 20.2
Saskatchewan 1,150,632 76 66.1
Earth 7,349,472,000 35,625 4.8
Region Population (%) Emissions (%) Emissions (%) / Population (%)
Canada 0.494% 2.05% 4.16
Saskatchewan 0.016% 0.21% 13.63
Earth 100.000% 100.00% 1.00
Canadian population data for July 2016 from: Statistics Canada, CANSIM Table 051-0001, http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a26
World population data from: United Nations https://esa.un.org/unpd/wpp/
Canadian Emissions Data for 2014 from Environment Canada (2016) National Inventory Report: https://www.ec.gc.ca/ges-ghg/default.asp?lang=En&n=662F9C56-1
Global emissions data for 2014 (without LULUCF/LUCF) from United Nations Statistics: http://unstats.un.org/unsd//ENVIRONMENT/qindicators.htm

There is also a more important reason for reducing GHG emissions at home. In a recent column, Andrew Coyne reminds us that climate change is a “collective action problem.” Climate change affects everyone, but it may be tempting for some regions to “free-ride” on the GHG reduction efforts of others. Imagine a potluck supper, and you show up without a dish of your own. You are a “free-rider” and enjoy the meal without any effort. Now, of course, if all guests showed up without a dish, there would be no supper.

Global GHG reduction is like this imagined potluck. For it to work, everyone has to bring a dish to the table. The Paris Agreement was a first step in this direction. To stretch the metaphor, countries around the world decided there will be a potluck; they committed to reduce emissions to keep warming below 2 degrees Celsius. It is now up to every country, and every province, to get in the kitchen and get cooking on emission reductions.

Missing Policies
Despite coming in at 53 pages, the White Paper is nearly silent on transportation emissions. This is a big oversight. Transportation emissions are a large and growing part of Saskatchewan’s emissions profile. Depending on how you divide them up, transportation emissions may actually be the largest source of GHGs in the province (see black bars in figure below).

blogimage12
(Source: Environment Canada, National Inventory Report 2015)

Some of the increase may be due to population growth in Saskatchewan, but transportation emissions have also increased substantially in per capita terms.

blogimage13
(Source: Environment Canada, National Inventory Report 2015; Population from Statistics Canada CANSIM Table 051-0001)

As noted above, the paper by Antweiler and Gulati credited BC’s carbon tax for reducing gasoline consumption and improving fleet efficiency by encouraging people to purchase more fuel efficient vehicles. The trend in Saskatchewan has been for drivers to purchase trucks and SUVs (see figure below). Just take a look around during your morning commute and ponder how many people now drive SUVs and large trucks. There has been a sea change in transportation choices in the past fifteen years.

blogimage14
(Source: Statistics Canada CANSIM 079-0003)

For every $10/tonne added to a national carbon price, gasoline prices go up by a little over 2 cents/litre. When the $50/tonne price floor comes into place in 2022, gasoline prices will have increased by 11 cents/litre. This may not seem like a lot; gasoline prices recently jumped by 7 cents/litre in one day due to market forces. But researchers Schaufele and Rivers (2013) have found that price increases due to carbon pricing are more “salient” to drivers. By studying reactions to BC’s carbon tax, Shaufele and Rivers (2013) found that, despite a lock-in to daily commutes and habits, drivers in BC found ways to reduce gas consumption in the short-term.

There is also a mental shift that occurs when we realize prices will continue to creep upwards, slowly, over time. As Antweiler and Gulati (2016) found, in the medium-term, when it comes time to purchase a new vehicle, a carbon tax will lead drivers to shift their purchase decisions and choose vehicles that are more fuel efficient.

The evidence from BC’s experience is clear; a carbon tax reduces transportation emissions. The White Paper failed to spell out how emissions from transportation will be reduced in Saskatchewan, and its credibility suffers because of the omission.

Conclusion
As the very least the White Paper is a clarification of the Saskatchewan government’s thinking on climate policy. On the positive side, the White Paper offers strong words on the need to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, “There is no doubt that the cost of inaction is far greater than the cost of smart, effective actions that actually reduce greenhouse gasses (GHGs)” (p. 4). Clearly, there is more work to be done to convince the Saskatchewan government that carbon pricing qualifies as one of these smart, effective actions.

So how do we move forward from here?

Rather than changing the conversation in Canada, perhaps it is best to think of the White Paper as the start of a conversation in Saskatchewan. Next door, Alberta developed a climate policy supported by industry and environmental groups alike. They invited a panel of experts to gather information, and conducted a provincial consultation. The result was the Climate Leadership Report.

It would be commendable to see the Government of Saskatchewan convene a Climate Leadership Panel in Saskatchewan. This panel would produce a fulsome review of the literature on carbon pricing, hybrid performance standards, and flexible regulations. It would model and quantify the likely GHG and GDP implications of the policies. And it would provide a suite of options for reducing emissions in the province. The panel would engage with citizens, businesses, and industry to understand their concerns and to seek out their ideas. It would produce a report, a green-and-white paper perhaps, outlining how Saskatchewan will reduce emissions and protect its economy. That would indeed be something to shift the national conversation.

 

References

Antweiler, Werner and Sumeet Gulati (2016) “Frugal Cars or Frugal Drivers? How Carbon and Fuel Taxes Influence the Choice and Use of Cars.” Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2778868 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2778868.

Bataille, Chris and Dave Sawyer (2016) Canadian Carbon Pricing Pathways: The economic and emission outcomes of leading policies. Final Report September 15, 2016. Available on-line at: http://www.enviroeconomics.org/single-post/2016/09/06/Assessing-Canadian-Carbon-Pricing-Pathways.

Beale, Elizabeth, Dale Beugin, Bev Dahlby, Don Drummond, Nancy Olewiler, Christopher Ragan (2015) Provincial Carbon Pricing and Competitiveness Pressures: Guidelines for Business and Policymakers. Ecofiscal Commission. Available on-line at: https://ecofiscal.ca/wp-content/uploads/2015/11/Ecofiscal-Commission-Carbon-Pricing-Competitiveness-Report-November-2015.pdf.

CBC News (2011) “AECL sold for $15M to SNC-Lavalin.” Available on-line at: http://www.cbc.ca/news/business/aecl-sold-for-15m-to-snc-lavalin-1.985786.

Coyne, Andrew (2016) “Andrew Coyne: Canada a small part of global emissions problem, but costs of inaction are not zero.” National Post October 12, 2016 Available on-line at: http://news.nationalpost.com/full-comment/andrew-coyne-canada-a-small-part-of-global-emissions-problem-but-costs-of-inaction-are-not-zero.

Government of Alberta (2016) “Carbon Levy and Rebates: Large Industrial Emitters.” Available on-line at: http://www.alberta.ca/climate-carbon-pricing.aspx#industry.

Government of Saskatchewan (2016) Climate Change White Paper. Available on-line at: http://www.saskatchewan.ca/government/news-and-media/2016/october/18/climate-change-plan.

Government of Saskatchewan (2009) Bill 95 ‘An Act respecting the Management and Reduction of Greenhouse Gases and Adaptation to Climate Change.’

http://www.qp.gov.sk.ca/documents/english/FirstRead/2009/Bill-95.pdf.

Jaccard, Mark (2016) “Want an effective climate policy? Heed the evidence.” Policy Options. Available on-line at: http://policyoptions.irpp.org/magazines/february-2016/want-an-effective-climatepolicy-heed-the-evidence/.

Jaccard, Mark, Mikela Hein and Tiffany Vass (2016) “Is Win-Win Possible? Can Canada’s Government Achieve Its Paris Commitment…and Get Re-Elected?” EMRG Working Paper. School of Resource and Environmental Management, Simon Fraser University. Available on-line at: http://rem-main.rem.sfu.ca/papers/jaccard/Jaccard-Hein-Vass%20CdnClimatePol%20EMRG-REM-SFU%20Sep%2020%202016.pdf.

Lee, Marc (2016) “Don’t believe the hype on BC’s carbon tax.” Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Behind the Numbers blog. Available on-line at: http://behindthenumbers.ca/2016/03/03/dont-believe-the-hype-on-bcs-carbon-tax/

Murray, Brian and Nicholas Rivers (2015) “British Columbia’s revenue-neutral carbon tax: A review of the latest “grand experiment” in environmental policy.” Energy Policy. 86, pp. 674-683. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2015.08.011.

Porter, Eduardo (2016) “Does a carbon tax work? Ask British Columbia.” New York Times, March 1, 2016. Available on-line at: http://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/02/business/does-a-carbon-tax-work-ask-british-columbia.html.

Statistics Canada (2016) CANSIM Statistical Tables. Search on-line at: http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/home-accueil?lang=eng.

Wall, Brad (2016) “A better emissions solution than a revenue-neutral carbon tax.” The Globe and Mail. Available on-line at: http://www.theglobeandmail.com/report-on-business/rob-commentary/a-better-emissions-solution-than-a-revenue-neutral-carbon-tax/article32352958/.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s